Brussels’ Overreaction: The Consequences of Counter-Tariffs Against China
OpinionSubsidies for key industries are controversial – but make far more economic sense than punitive tariffs on imports. A guest article.
The EU responds to China’s state subsidies with punitive tariffs – but is this really the right approach? In their guest article, Professor Klaus Schmidt of LMU Munich and ZEW President Professor Achim Wambach argue that counter-tariffs not only burden trade but also jeopardise important global goals such as climate protection and security of supply. Instead, they argue for a nuanced industrial policy that uses subsidies wisely to strengthen European interests without escalating international conflicts.
It’s not without a certain irony: the European Commission is imposing (WTO-compliant) punitive tariffs on imports of electric cars from China because their manufacturers are heavily subsidised. At the same time, there are calls for more domestic state aid: Former Italian Prime Minister Letta, in a report for the Commission on the Single Market, stresses the need for a more flexible state aid governance framework as part of a new industrial policy, giving European states more freedom to support their companies. So, basically, subsidising is only bad if it’s done by someone else.
Indeed, there is a strong case for an active industrial policy in Europe, too. The transition to climate neutrality won’t happen on its own, even though the EU has successfully established emissions trading as a key tool for climate protection. Ensuring security of supply in times of crisis, for example for medicines and raw materials, also requires active government intervention. While securing supply chains is also in the individual economic interest of companies, the wider economic damage caused by disrupted supply chains is not fully taken into account.
This raises the question of how to deal with subsidies from third countries. These may distort competition in the Single Market, but they also have advantages for local customers: if Chinese taxpayers subsidise their solar industry so that the EU can benefit from cheaper solar panels, that’s good for Europeans who want to install them on their homes.
Another argument comes into play: the overarching goal of climate policy is to achieve global climate neutrality, a global public good. When third countries subsidise their green industries, it helps all nations meet their climate goals at a lower cost. China’s subsidies, for example, also contribute to global CO2 reductions. From this perspective, it’s unwise for the EU to counter Chinese subsidies for solar panels and electric cars.
Even the controversial Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) in the US, a massive subsidy programme, can be seen as an opportunity: these subsidies not only lower the cost of climate protection, but also reduce dependence on China and contribute to more secure supply chains. These supply chains, in turn, often have the characteristics of global public goods. Investments in new extraction sites or incentives for increased stockpiling make supply chains less likely to be disrupted during crises.
To be clear: well-designed subsidies can contribute to climate change mitigation and resilience in Europe. However, this is not a blanket endorsement of state aid or increased state control over the economy. Subsidies distort competition, increase lobbying and cost taxpayers’ money. Not every subsidy currently proposed in the name of climate protection and resilience is therefore beneficial. For example, the Scientific Advisory Board of the German Federal Ministry of Economic Affairs recommends that the transition of basic industries to climate neutrality should be promoted primarily through green lead markets, with as little reliance as possible on subsidies in the form of climate protection contracts.
Conflict with China should not escalate
Globally, it’s counterproductive to pay subsidies for companies to move production to their home country. This exacerbates supply shortages for other countries in times of crisis or when borders are closed.
A better model might be Germany’s pandemic preparedness contracts: vaccine manufacturers are paid to prepare production in Germany to ensure supply in the event of a new pandemic. As long as these production facilities are additional to existing ones and not simply relocated, they contribute to security of supply beyond Germany.
What happens next? The EU still wants to negotiate with China to avoid tariffs, which would be the best way to resolve the conflict peacefully. However, there is a risk that the negotiations will fail. If that happens, imposing punitive tariffs on goods that are crucial to global goals would be a bad idea.
The IRA, the Green Deal and China’s subsidies are helping to meet the Paris climate goals and contribute to supply chain resilience. The subsidy race, therefore, has its benefits. The EU should keep this in mind when discussing how to deal with third-country subsidies.
The guest article was first published in WirtschaftsWoche [€] (in German).